Cournot competition is an economic model used to describe an industry structure in which companies compete on the amount of output they will produce, which they decide on independently of each other and at the same time. It is named after Antoine Augustin Cournot (1801–1877) who was inspired by observing competition in a spring water duopoly . It has the following features:
56-481: Cournot may refer to: Cournot competition , an economic model of duopoly Surname Antoine Augustin Cournot (1801–1877), French philosopher, mathematician and economist Michel Cournot (1922–2007), French journalist, screenwriter and film director Topics referred to by the same term [REDACTED] This disambiguation page lists articles associated with
112-524: A − χ 3 b {\displaystyle q^{*}={\frac {a-\chi }{3b}}} . This equilibrium value describes the optimal level of output for firms 1 and 2, where each firm is producing an output quantity of q ∗ {\displaystyle q^{*}} . So, at equilibrium, the total market output Q {\displaystyle Q} will be Q = q 1 ∗ + q 2 ∗ = 2 (
168-697: A − χ ) 3 b {\displaystyle Q=q_{1}^{*}+q_{2}^{*}={\frac {2(a-\chi )}{3b}}} . The revenues accruing to the two proprietors are p D 1 {\displaystyle pD_{1}} and p D 2 {\displaystyle pD_{2}} , i.e., f ( D 1 + D 2 ) ⋅ D 1 {\displaystyle f(D_{1}+D_{2})\cdot D_{1}} and f ( D 1 + D 2 ) ⋅ D 2 {\displaystyle f(D_{1}+D_{2})\cdot D_{2}} . The first proprietor maximizes profit by optimizing over
224-486: A graph. If the first proprietor was providing quantity x l {\displaystyle x_{\textsf {l}}} , then the second proprietor would adopt quantity y l {\displaystyle y_{\textsf {l}}} from the red curve to maximize his or her revenue. But then, by similar reasoning, the first proprietor will adjust his supply to x ll {\displaystyle x_{\textsf {ll}}} to give him or her
280-736: A proprietor can adjust his supply "en modifiant correctement le prix". Again, this is nonsense: it is impossible for a single price to be simultaneously under the control of two suppliers. If there is a single price, then it must be determined by the market as a consequence of the proprietors' decisions on matters under their individual control. Cournot's account threw his English translator (Nathaniel Bacon) so completely off-balance that his words were corrected to "properly adjusting his price". Edgeworth regarded equality of price in Cournot as "a particular condition, not... abstractly necessary in cases of imperfect competition". Jean Magnan de Bornier says that in Cournot's theory "each owner will use price as
336-445: A translation to be made by Nathaniel Bacon in 1897. Reactions to this aspect of Cournot's theory have ranged from searing condemnation to half-hearted endorsement. It has received sympathy in recent years as a contribution to game theory rather than economics. James W. Friedman explains: In current language and interpretation, Cournot postulated a particular game to represent an oligopolistic market... The maths in Cournot's book
392-471: A value of 0). So, the root m 1 {\displaystyle m_{1}} of the first equation is necessarily greater than the root m 2 {\displaystyle m_{2}} of the second equation. We have seen that Cournot's system reduces to the equation 2 f ( D ) + D f ′ ( D ) = 0 {\displaystyle 2f(D)+Df'(D)=0} . D {\displaystyle D}
448-447: A variable to control quantity" without saying how one price can govern two quantities. A. J. Nichol claimed that Cournot's theory makes no sense unless "prices are directly determined by buyers". Shapiro , perhaps in despair, remarked that "the actual process of price formation in Cournot's theory is somewhat mysterious". Cournot's duopolists are not true profit-maximizers. Either supplier could increase his or her profits by cutting out
504-468: A very misleading conclusion, and he reworked it using prices rather than quantities as the strategic variables, thus showing that the equilibrium price was simply the competitive price. His book Thermodynamique states in Chapter XII, that thermodynamic entropy and temperature are only defined for reversible processes . He was one of the first people to state this publicly. In 1858 he was elected
560-428: A way of describing the competition with a market for spring water dominated by two suppliers (a duopoly ). The model was one of a number that Cournot set out "explicitly and with mathematical precision" in the volume. Specifically, Cournot constructed profit functions for each firm, and then used partial differentiation to construct a function representing a firm's best response for given (exogenous) output levels of
616-417: Is 0, but D 2 f ( D 2 ) {\displaystyle D_{2}f(D_{2})} is the monetary value of an aggregate sales quantity D 2 {\displaystyle D_{2}} , and the turning point of this value is a maximum. Evidently, the sales quantity which maximizes monetary value is reached before the maximum possible sales quantity (which corresponds to
SECTION 10
#1732764811199672-462: Is 0, the two equations reduce to: The first of these corresponds to the quantity D 2 {\displaystyle D_{2}} sold when the price is zero (which is the maximum quantity the public is willing to consume), while the second states that the derivative of D 2 f ( D 2 ) {\displaystyle D_{2}f(D_{2})} with respect to D 2 {\displaystyle D_{2}}
728-588: Is elementary and the presentation not difficult to follow. The account below follows Cournot's words and diagrams closely. The diagrams were presumably included as an oversized plate in the original edition, and are missing from some modern reprints. Cournot's discussion of oligopoly draws on two theoretical advances made in earlier pages of his book. Both have passed (with some adjustment) into microeconomic theory, particularly within subfield of Industrial Organization where Cournot's assumptions can be relaxed to study various Market Structures and Industries, for example,
784-473: Is functionally related to p {\displaystyle p} via f {\displaystyle f} in one direction and F {\displaystyle F} in the other. If we re-express this equation in terms of p {\displaystyle p} , it tells us that F ( p ) + 2 p F ′ ( p ) = 0 {\displaystyle F(p)+2pF'(p)=0} , which can be compared with
840-440: Is given by C ( q i ) = χ q i {\displaystyle C(q_{i})=\chi q_{i}} , where χ {\displaystyle \chi } is the marginal cost. This assumption tells us that both firms face the same cost-per-unit produced. Therefore, as each firm's profit is equal to its revenues minus costs, where revenue equals the number of units produced multiplied by
896-524: Is linear and of the form p = a − b Q {\displaystyle p=a-bQ} . So, the inverse demand function can then be rewritten as p = a − b q 1 − b q 2 {\displaystyle p=a-bq_{1}-bq_{2}} . Now, substituting our equation for price in place of p ( Q ) {\displaystyle p(Q)} we can write each firm's profit function as: As firms are assumed to be profit-maximizers,
952-569: Is most easily done by adding and subtracting them, turning them into: Thus, we see that the two proprietors supply equal quantities, and that the total quantity sold is the root of a single nonlinear equation in D {\displaystyle D} . Cournot goes further than this simple solution, investigating the stability of the equilibrium. Each of his original equations defines a relation between D 1 {\displaystyle D_{1}} and D 2 {\displaystyle D_{2}} which may be drawn on
1008-667: Is named for him, known as the Bertrand Paradox . In 1849, he was the first to define real numbers using what is now termed a Dedekind cut . Bertrand translated into French Carl Friedrich Gauss 's work concerning the theory of errors and the method of least squares . Concerning economics , he reviewed the work on oligopoly theory, specifically the Cournot Competition Model (1838) of French mathematician Antoine Augustin Cournot . His Bertrand Competition Model (1883) argued that Cournot had reached
1064-563: Is set at a level such that demand equals the total quantity produced by all firms. Each firm takes the quantity set by its competitors as a given, evaluates its residual demand, and then behaves as a monopoly . The state of equilibrium... is therefore stable ; i.e., if either of the producers, misled as to his true interest, leaves it temporarily, he will be brought back to it. Antoine Augustin Cournot (1801–1877) first outlined his theory of competition in his 1838 volume Recherches sur les Principes Mathématiques de la Théorie des Richesses as
1120-581: Is that each [producer] assumes his rival's price will remain fixed, while his own price is adjusted. Under this hypothesis each would undersell the other as long as any profit remained, so that the final result would be identical with the result of unlimited competition. Fisher seemed to regard Bertrand as having been the first to present this model, and it has since entered the literature as Bertrand competition . Joseph Bertrand Joseph Louis François Bertrand ( French pronunciation: [ʒozɛf lwi fʁɑ̃swa bɛʁtʁɑ̃] ; 11 March 1822 – 5 April 1900)
1176-439: Is the p {\displaystyle p} for which this curve intersects the line u = p {\displaystyle u=p} , while the duopoly price is given by the intersection of the curve with the steeper line u = 2 p {\displaystyle u=2p} . Regardless of the shape of the curve, its intersection with u = 2 p {\displaystyle u=2p} occurs to
SECTION 20
#17327648111991232-401: Is the "not conjecture" that each firm aims to maximize profits, based on the expectation that its own output decision will not have an effect on the decisions of its rivals. Price is a commonly known decreasing function of total output. All firms know N {\displaystyle N} , the total number of firms in the market, and take the output of the others as given. The market price
1288-403: Is the amount supplied by proprietor i {\displaystyle i} . Each proprietor is assumed to know the amount being supplied by his or her rival, and to adjust his or her own supply in the light of it to maximize his or her profits. The position of equilibrium is one in which neither proprietor is inclined to adjust the quantity supplied. It needs mental contortions to imagine
1344-409: Is the derivative of F ( p ) {\displaystyle F(p)} ). Cournot insists that each duopolist seeks independently to maximize profits, and this restriction is essential, since Cournot tells us that if they came to an understanding between each other so as each to obtain the maximum possible revenue, then completely different results would be obtained, indistinguishable from
1400-493: Is why we set the above equations equal to zero. Now that we have two equations describing the states at which each firm is producing at the profit-maximizing quantity, we can simply solve this system of equations to obtain each firm's optimal level of output, q 1 , q 2 {\displaystyle q_{1},q_{2}} for firms 1 and 2 respectively. So, we obtain: These functions describe each firm's optimal (profit-maximizing) quantity of output given
1456-535: The Stackelberg Competition model. Cournot's discussion of monopoly influenced later writers such as Edward Chamberlin and Joan Robinson during the 1930s revival of interest in imperfect competition . Cournot was wary of psychological notions of demand, defining it simply as the amount sold of a particular good (helped along by the fact that the French word débit , meaning 'sales quantity', has
1512-677: The amount sold have an influence on Cournot's demand curve. Cournot remarks that the demand curve will usually be a decreasing function of price, and that the total value of the good sold is p F ( p ) {\displaystyle pF(p)} , which will generally increase to a maximum and then decline towards 0. The condition for a maximum is that the derivative of p F ( p ) {\displaystyle pF(p)} , i.e., F ( p ) + p F ′ ( p ) {\displaystyle F(p)+pF'(p)} , should be 0 (where F ′ ( p ) {\displaystyle F'(p)}
1568-414: The consumer's point of view from those entailed by monopoly. Cournot presents a mathematically correct analysis of the equilibrium condition corresponding to a certain logically consistent model of duopolist behaviour. However his model is not stated and is not particularly natural ( Shapiro remarked that observed practice constituted a "natural objection to the Cournot quantity model" ), and "his words and
1624-488: The course of the École Polytechnique as an auditor. From age eleven to seventeen, he obtained two bachelor's degrees, a license and a PhD with a thesis concerning the mathematical theory of electricity, and was admitted to the 1839 entrance examination of the École Polytechnique. Bertrand was a professor at the École Polytechnique and Collège de France , and was a member of the Paris Academy of Sciences of which he
1680-473: The diagram from the intersection of u = n p {\displaystyle u=np} with the curve. Hence, the price diminishes indefinitely as the number of proprietors increases. With an infinite number of proprietors, the price becomes zero; or more generally, if we allow for costs of production, the price becomes the marginal cost. The French mathematician Joseph Bertrand , when reviewing Walras 's Théorie Mathématique de la Richesse Sociale ,
1736-523: The equation F ( p ) + p F ′ ( p ) = 0 {\displaystyle F(p)+pF'(p)=0} obtained earlier for monopoly. If we plot another variable u {\displaystyle u} against p {\displaystyle p} , then we may draw a curve of the function u = − F ( p ) F ′ ( p ) {\displaystyle u=-{\frac {F(p)}{F'(p)}}} . The monopoly price
Cournot - Misplaced Pages Continue
1792-525: The equilibrium levels as neither firm has an incentive to change their level of output as doing so will harm the firm at the benefit of their rival. Now substituting in q ∗ {\displaystyle q^{*}} for q 1 , q 2 {\displaystyle q_{1},q_{2}} and solving we obtain the symmetric (same for each firm) output quantity in Equilibrium as q ∗ =
1848-495: The equilibrium position it follows that the equilibrium is stable, but Cournot remarks that if the red and blue curves were interchanged then this would cease to be true. He adds that it is easy to see that the corresponding diagram would be inadmissible since, for instance, it is necessarily the case that m 1 > m 2 {\displaystyle m_{1}>m_{2}} . To verify this, notice that when D 1 {\displaystyle D_{1}}
1904-425: The first-order conditions (F.O.C.s) for each firm are: The F.O.C.s state that firm i {\displaystyle i} is producing at the profit-maximizing level of output when the marginal cost ( MC {\displaystyle {\text{MC}}} ) is equal to the marginal revenue ( MR {\displaystyle {\text{MR}}} ). Intuitively, this suggests that firms will produce up to
1960-405: The inverse of F {\displaystyle F} is written f {\displaystyle f} and the market-clearing price is given by p = f ( D ) {\displaystyle p=f(D)} , where D = D 1 + D 2 {\displaystyle D=D_{1}+D_{2}} and D i {\displaystyle D_{i}}
2016-491: The left of (i.e., at a lower price than) its intersection with u = p {\displaystyle u=p} . Hence, prices are lower under duopoly than under monopoly, and quantities sold are accordingly higher. When there are n {\displaystyle n} proprietors, the price equation becomes F ( p ) + n p F ′ ( p ) = 0 {\displaystyle F(p)+npF'(p)=0} . The price can be read from
2072-434: The market price, we can denote the profit functions for firm 1 and firm 2 as follows: In the above profit functions we have price as a function of total output which we denote as Q {\displaystyle Q} and for two firms we must have Q = q 1 + q 2 {\displaystyle Q=q_{1}+q_{2}} . For example's sake, let us assume that price (inverse demand function)
2128-448: The market-clearing price, which is determined by the demand function F {\displaystyle F} and the aggregate supply. He or she sells the water at this price, passing the proceeds back to the proprietors. The consumer demand D {\displaystyle D} for mineral water at price p {\displaystyle p} is denoted by F ( p ) {\displaystyle F(p)} ;
2184-412: The mathematics do not quite match". His model can be grasped more easily if we slightly embellish it. Suppose that there are two owners of mineral water springs, each able to produce unlimited quantities at zero price. Suppose that instead of selling water to the public they offer it to a middle man. Each proprietor notifies the middle man of the quantity he or she intends to produce. The middle man finds
2240-596: The maximum return as shown by the blue curve when D 2 {\displaystyle D_{2}} is equal to y l {\displaystyle y_{\textsf {l}}} . This will lead to the second proprietor adapting to the supply value y ll {\displaystyle y_{\textsf {ll}}} , and so forth until equilibrium is reached at the point of intersection i {\displaystyle i} , whose coordinates are ( x , y ) {\displaystyle (x,y)} . Since proprietors move towards
2296-511: The middle man and cornering the market by marginally undercutting his or her rival; thus the middle man can be seen as a mechanism for restricting competition. Cournot's model of competition is typically presented for the case of a duopoly market structure; the following example provides a straightforward analysis of the Cournot model for the case of Duopoly. Therefore, suppose we have a market consisting of only two firms which we will call firm 1 and firm 2. For simplicity, we assume each firm faces
Cournot - Misplaced Pages Continue
2352-486: The other abandoned the struggle, has nothing more to gain from reducing his price. One major objection to this is that there is no solution under this assumption, in that there is no limit to the downward movement... If Cournot's formulation conceals this obvious result, it is because he most inadvertently introduces as D and D' the two proprietors' respective outputs, and by considering them as independent variables, he assumes that should either proprietor change his output then
2408-412: The other firm(s) in the market. He then showed that a stable equilibrium occurs where these functions intersect (i.e., the simultaneous solution of the best response functions of each firm). The consequence of this is that in equilibrium, each firm's expectations of how other firms will act are shown to be correct; when all is revealed, no firm wants to change its output decision. This idea of stability
2464-410: The other proprietor's output could remain constant. It quite obviously could not. Pareto was unimpressed by Bertrand's critique, concluding from it that Bertrand 'wrote his article without consulting the books he criticised'. Irving Fisher outlined a model of duopoly similar to the one Bertrand had accused Cournot of analysing incorrectly: A more natural hypothesis, and one often tacitly adopted,
2520-423: The parameter D 1 {\displaystyle D_{1}} under his control, giving the condition that the partial derivative of his profit with respect to D 1 {\displaystyle D_{1}} should be 0, and the mirror-image reasoning applies to his or her rival. We thus get the equations: The equlibirum position is found by solving these two equations simultaneously. This
2576-578: The point where it remains profitable to do so, as any further production past this point will mean that MC > MR {\displaystyle {\text{MC}}>{\text{MR}}} , and therefore production beyond this point results in the firm losing money for each additional unit produced. Notice that at the profit-maximizing quantity where MC = MR {\displaystyle {\text{MC}}={\text{MR}}} , we must have MC − MR = 0 {\displaystyle {\text{MC}}-{\text{MR}}=0} which
2632-463: The price firms face in the market, p {\displaystyle p} , the marginal cost, χ {\displaystyle \chi } , and output quantity of rival firms. The functions can be thought of as describing a firm's "Best Response" to the other firm's level of output. We can now find a Cournot- Nash Equilibrium using our "Best Response" functions above for the output quantity of firms 1 and 2. Recall that both firms face
2688-410: The same cost-per-unit ( χ {\displaystyle \chi } ) and price ( p {\displaystyle p} ). Therefore, using this symmetrical relationship between firms we find the equilibrium quantity by fixing q 1 = q 2 = q ∗ {\displaystyle q_{1}=q_{2}=q^{*}} . We can be sure this setup gives us
2744-440: The same initial letter as demande , meaning 'demand' ). He formalised it mathematically as follows: We will regard the sales quantity or annual demand D {\displaystyle D} , for any commodity, to be a function F ( p ) {\displaystyle F(p)} of its price. It follows that his demand curves do some of the work of modern supply curves, since producers who are able to limit
2800-437: The same marginal cost. That is, for a given firm i {\displaystyle i} 's output quantity, denoted q i {\displaystyle q_{i}} where i ∈ { 1 , 2 } {\displaystyle i\in \{1,2\}} , firm i {\displaystyle i} 's cost of producing q i {\displaystyle q_{i}} units of output
2856-507: The same market behaviour arising without a middle man. A feature of Cournot's model is that a single price applies to both proprietors. He justified this assumption by saying that "dès lors le prix est nécessairement le même pour l'un et l'autre propriétaire". de Bornier expands on this by saying that "the obvious conclusion that only a single price can exist at a given moment" follows from "an essential assumption concerning his model, [namely] product homogeneity". Later on Cournot writes that
SECTION 50
#17327648111992912-543: The title Cournot . If an internal link led you here, you may wish to change the link to point directly to the intended article. Retrieved from " https://en.wikipedia.org/w/index.php?title=Cournot&oldid=675871061 " Categories : Disambiguation pages Disambiguation pages with surname-holder lists Hidden categories: Short description is different from Wikidata All article disambiguation pages All disambiguation pages Cournot competition An essential assumption of this model
2968-466: Was a French mathematician whose work emphasized number theory , differential geometry , probability theory , economics and thermodynamics . Joseph Bertrand was the son of physician Alexandre Jacques François Bertrand and the brother of archaeologist Alexandre Bertrand . His father died when Joseph was only nine years old; by that time he had learned a substantial amount of mathematics and could speak Latin fluently. At eleven years old he attended
3024-552: Was drawn to Cournot's book by Walras's high praise of it. Bertrand was critical of Cournot's reasoning and assumptions, Bertrand claimed that "removing the symbols would reduce the book to just a few pages". His summary of Cournot's theory of duopoly has remained influential: Cournot assumes that one of the proprietors will reduce his price to attract buyers to him, and that the other will in turn reduce his price even more to attract buyers back to him. They will only stop undercutting each other in this way, when either proprietor, even if
3080-465: Was later taken up and built upon as a description of Nash equilibria , of which Cournot equilibria are a subset. Cournot's economic theory was little noticed until Léon Walras credited him as a forerunner. This led to an unsympathetic review of Cournot's book by Joseph Bertrand which in turn received heavy criticism. Irving Fisher found Cournot's treatment of oligopoly "brilliant and suggestive, but not free from serious objections". He arranged for
3136-499: Was the permanent secretary for twenty-six years. He conjectured, in 1845, that there is at least one prime number between n and 2 n − 2 for every n > 3. Chebyshev proved this conjecture, now termed Bertrand's postulate , in 1850. He was also famous for two paradoxes of probability , known now as Bertrand's Paradox and the Paradox of Bertrand's box . There is another paradox concerning game theory that
#198801