The Eighth Five-Year Plan of the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics (USSR) was a set of production goals and guidelines for administering the economy from 1966 to 1970—part of a series of such plans used by the USSR from 1928 until its dissolution. "Directives" for the plan involved set high goals for industrial production, especially in vehicles and appliances. These directives for the Eighth Five-Year Plan was approved by the Central Committee of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union and by the 23rd Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union but no final version was apparently ever ratified by the Supreme Soviet of the Soviet Union . Nevertheless, some of the changes envisioned were made.
63-467: The Eighth Five-Year Plan called for various changes in the administration of the economy. Some planning was re-centralized, reversing a policy for regional councils created in 1957. But individual plant directors gained more power to set policy. The plan implemented economic reforms announced in 1965 , which linked wages more closely to output. Given the significant economic transition envisioned by these reforms, and their greater emphasis on economic realism,
126-700: A 15% increase in military spending. During the failed approval process, the goals of the plan were reduced twice. Technically, the Eighth Five-Year Plan was the seventh Five-Year Plan: there was no Seventh Five-Year Plan, as the Sixth Five-Year Plan was interrupted in 1959 by the "Seven-Year Plan". 1965 Soviet economic reform The 1965 Soviet economic reform , sometimes called the Kosygin reform ( Russian : Косыгинская реформа ) or Liberman reform , named after E.G. Liberman,
189-439: A businesslike approach, a feeling for the new, and the ability to use production resources in each specific circumstance with maximum effectiveness, herein is the essence of the new demands. In previous eras, an important layer of administrative control over production had been sovnarkhozy (совнархо́зы, a contraction of words meaning "Council of National Economy"), the regional economic councils created on December 1, 1917, under
252-465: A centralized system to manage its economy. In this system, a single bureaucracy created economic plans, which assigned workers to jobs, set wages, dictated resource allocation, established the levels of trade with other countries, and planned the course of technological progress. Retail prices for consumer goods were fixed at levels intended for market clearing . The prices of wholesale goods were fixed, also, but these served an accounting function more than
315-420: A coal mine and factories producing clothing, shoes, and heavy lifting equipment. The coal mine, in particular, reportedly became more profitable after shifting to a system using bonuses and more independent decisionmaking. Some of the experimental plants ran into problems, however, due to the unreliability of suppliers continuing to operate on the old system. The Mayak plant faced a dilemma in trying to implement
378-457: A contractual exchange relationship. The authors of the reforms knew from the outset that changes would take effect gradually, based on the careful writing of plans through the years 1966 and 1967. The first 43 enterprises, along with several "experiments" for which planning began before the September 1965 Plenum, shifted to the new model at the beginning of 1966. Transfer of another 180–200
441-460: A market mechanism. Collective farms also paid centrally determined prices for the supplies they needed, and unlike other sectors their workers received wages directly dependent on the profitability of the operation. Although Soviet enterprises were theoretically governed by the principle of khozraschet ( Russian : хозрасчёт , lit. 'business bookkeeping', or "accounting")—which required them to meet planners' expectations within
504-541: A return to ministries as core administrators. His plan resembled the ministry system under Stalin, but with a smaller number: nine all-Union ministries organized by industry (e.g., Ministry of Light Industry, Ministry of the Radio Industry, Ministry of the Chemical Industry) and eleven supervising operations within each union-republic. The latter regional agencies reported both to the local council and to
567-558: A shift to a five-day work week . The plan set the stage for wider distribution of things like television sets, refrigerators, and washing machines. Although unemployment had been officially abolished, there were in fact people without jobs in regions such as Tajikistan, Moldavia, Moscow oblast, Mari Autonomous Republic, and Uzbekistan, and one purpose of the plan was to create new work projects in these areas. (The policy of no unemployment had also led to "superfluous workers" assigned non-essential jobs in various factories.) Kosygin reaffirmed
630-426: A single area. The economic reform of 1957 reintroduced the sovnarkhozy , 104 in number, to govern production by region. Where applicable, these corresponded closely with the boundaries of the oblasty (political jurisdictions). Complaints immediately arose that these councils did not optimize overall production chains, due to their regional focus, and that they conflicted with the authority of Gosplan . In 1962,
693-607: A socialist framework. Under Lenin, the New Economic Policy had allowed and used the concepts of profit and incentives for regulation of the Soviet economy. Stalin transformed this policy rapidly with the collectivization of farms and nationalization of industry, which was the result of the acceleration of central planning as exemplified by the " Five-Year Plans ". Since about 1930, the Soviet Union had used
SECTION 10
#1732772339686756-610: A total increase in output of 25%. The budget for the plan was 310,000,000,000 rubles , the allocation for which was specified in less detail than previously. Directives for the Plan were approved by the 23rd Congress of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union , which convened 37 days after a draft of the directives was published. The Directives were then referred to Gosplan , the USSR's central planning agency, for elaboration into
819-479: Is necessary to reconstruct the whole system of prices, the system of incentives, in short, to alter a great deal in the existing forms and methods of economic management. If this is not done, then the introduction of profit will bring about no effect whatsoever. The plan also called for the cultivation of a new breed of managers; As Kosygin in Pravda (September 28, 1965): ...initiative based on know-how, efficiency,
882-467: The 1977 Soviet Constitution , the head of government was the leader of the highest executive and administrative organ of state. The head of government was appointed by and accountable to the Supreme Soviet (and its Presidium ). The head of government was tasked with resolving all state administrative duties within the jurisdiction of the USSR to the degree which were not the responsibility of
945-519: The Lenin Prize in 1965. The battle between "optimal" planning and convention planning raged throughout the 1960s. Another tendency in economic planning emphasized "normative value of processing", or the importance of needs and wants in evaluating the value of production. Major changes throughout the Soviet world became possible in 1964 with the ousting of Nikita Khrushchev and the rise of Alexei Kosygin and Leonid Brezhnev . Economic policy
1008-429: The capital it retained: working capital , equipment, and surplus stocks. Enterprises were to submit annual plans, called tekhpromfinplans (from Russian : техпромфинплан ( ru:Техпрофинплан ) - technical and financial production plan) , stipulating production plans by quarter and month. Higher-ups would then approve these plans (or not) and allocate supplies and money. The enterprise then sells its products, within
1071-510: The de facto leader was the party's General Secretary, with Stalin and his successor Nikita Khrushchev also serving as premier. Twelve individuals held the post. Lenin's First Government was created on 6 July 1923 by the Central Executive Committee with Lenin as its first chairman. The government was empowered to initiate decrees and legislation that were binding throughout the USSR. The longest serving premier in
1134-446: The 104 sovnarkhozy were consolidated into 47 larger jurisdictions (one of which controlled all of Uzbekistan, Turkmenistan, Tadzhikistan, and Kirgizia). However, by 1962–1963, the sovnarkhozy were becoming subordinate to numerous other agencies and organizations. Gosplan was to be stripped of its planning authority in favor of a revitalized VSNKh. Kosygin took aim at these "outdated forms of management" and included in his 1965 speech
1197-585: The 1966 plan called for production of passenger cars (such as the Moskvitch 408 ) to increase to 53% of the total. The increased production of vehicles would be made possible with outside technical assistance—most notably from Fiat , in the construction of the AvtoVAZ plant in Togliatti. The plan also called for agricultural output to expand more than twice as fast, annually, as it did from 1958 to 1965, for
1260-545: The Eighth Five-Year Plan set relatively modest production goals. Introducing the plan at the 23rd Congress, Premier Alexei Kosygin said the USSR would repudiate "subjectivism in deciding economic matters as amateurish contempt for the data of science and practical experience". He focused on the plan's potential to improve quality of life for individuals, saying, "Comrades! Construction of communism and improvement in people's welfare are inseparable. Along these lines, Kosygin promised higher wages, lower prices on consumer goods, and
1323-542: The Soviet Union following the removal of Nikita Khrushchev —and ratified by the Central Committee in September 1965. They reflected some long-simmering wishes of the USSR's mathematically-oriented economic planners, and initiated the shift towards increased decentralization in the process of economic planning . The reforms, coinciding with the Eighth Five-Year Plan , led to continued growth of
SECTION 20
#17327723396861386-647: The Soviet economy. Aircraft engineer O. Antonov published an article in Izvestia on November 22, 1961, with the title "For All and For Oneself"—advocating more power for enterprise directors. A widely publicized economic rationale for reform came from Evsei Liberman of the Kharkov Institute of Engineering and Economics . An article by Liberman on this topic, titled "Plans, Profits, and Bonuses" appeared in Pravda in September 1962. Liberman, influenced by
1449-496: The Soviet economy. The success of said reforms was short-lived, and with the events of Prague in 1968 , fueled by Moscow's implementation of the reforms in Eastern Bloc countries, led to the reforms being curtailed. Economists like Lev Gatovsky and Liberman were instrumental in framing the theoretical underpinnings of the Soviet economic reforms of the 1960s, advocating for the use of profit motives and market mechanisms within
1512-806: The Supreme Soviet or its Presidium. The head of government managed the national economy, formulated the five-year plans and ensured socio-cultural development. It functioned as the most influential office of government and nominally the most influential office until the establishment of the Office of the President of the Soviet Union in 1990. Vladimir Lenin and Joseph Stalin died in office of natural causes, and three premiers resigned— Alexei Kosygin , Nikolai Tikhonov and Ivan Silayev . Another three were concurrently party leader and head of government (Lenin, Stalin and Nikita Khrushchev ). The one who spent
1575-535: The allocation of money to a fund, which could be disbursed according to a pre-defined sequence. The funds first went to pay for capital—including interest paid to Gosbank , the State Bank. Then, they went to the new incentive funds. Finally, they could be used by an enterprise to expand its capital for operations. Any profit extending above the maximum for spending would go to the central budget. The three "incentive" funds were: Formerly, bonuses had come from
1638-601: The appropriate inputs available to the enterprises. A price revision, the first since 1955, was announced in mid-1966, apparently following some non-trivial internal disputes. The revision called for moderate re-alignment of prices, to conform more with production costs, and went into effect in July 1967. Wholesale fuel and ore prices increased substantially. Prices on consumer goods did not officially increase at all; yet consumers paid higher prices for things they wanted and needed, since newer, more expensive goods were introduced to
1701-403: The bureaucracy. Officials the higher administrative levels (i.e., the ministries), continued to issue orders at odds with the profitability plans of the enterprise managers. Some traditional problems—such as accumulation (which undercut profitability) of surplus valuable supplies, lest they be needed later in a time of shortage—persisted. Gossnab and the ministries were blamed for failing to make
1764-597: The central budget. These payments of "free" remaining profits substantially exceeded capital charges. However, central planners were not satisfied with the impact of the reform. In particular, they observed that wages had increased without a commensurate rise in productivity. Many of the specific changes were revised or reversed in 1969–1971. The reforms somewhat reduced the role of the Party in micromanaging economic operations. The backlash against economic reformism joined with opposition to political liberalization to trigger
1827-407: The central ministry with jurisdiction over their production type. Gosplan had the responsibility for creating annual and long-term plans, and for guiding development and resource management. Gossnab became the primary coordinator of material-technical supply, and was charged with large-scale analysis (possibly using computers) to increase supply chain efficiency. The 1965 reforms somewhat altered
1890-527: The centrally mandated experimental reforms, while simultaneously receiving contradictory orders from the local sovnarkhoz (regional council). The reform was administered by the Central Committee of the Communist Party of the Soviet Union and the Council of Ministers . It consisted of five "groups of activities": The most important changes resulting from the Liberman/Kosygin reforms involved
1953-456: The constraints of the plan. It is empowered to reject or return (within ten days) unneeded inputs to the supplier. The key change which represented "decentralization" was the delegation of responsibility over modernization investments. However, modernization plans remained subject to central approval, as well as approval from the bank which lent the money. The amount of development expected under these auspices fell far short of expectations, as
Eighth five-year plan (Soviet Union) - Misplaced Pages Continue
2016-630: The control of the Supreme Soviet of the National Economy (VSNKh, Vesenkha , a similar contraction). These councils spelled the end of a short-lived phase of worker control over production, which the Bolsheviks regarded as inefficient. Under the New Economic Policy beginning in 1921, enterprises were classified based on their relative interdependence (and necessity to war production) or autonomy (i.e. those "endowed with complete financial and commercial independence"). The many enterprises in
2079-490: The economic "optimizers", argued for the (re)introduction of profitability as a core economic indicator. Liberman advanced the idea that the social interest could be advanced through careful setting of microeconomic parameters: "What is profitable for society should be profitable for every enterprise." These proposals were controversial, and criticized especially as regressions towards a capitalist economic system. Critics also argued that reliance on profitability would skew
2142-424: The effect of Khrushchev-era wage reforms . An experimental system introduced at some enterprises offered extra bonuses for specific achievements—not just as a portion of total profits. For example, engineers using fuel more efficiently (during a shortage) could receive large premia calculated as a percentage of the money they saved. Along with more direct responsibility for the wage fund, enterprises also gained
2205-473: The end of the year, 7,000 industrial enterprises (out of 45,000), 1,500 trucking firms (out of 4,100), and all 25 railroad systems had transferred. Together these made up the backbone of Soviet industry. They were followed by smaller enterprises: 11,000 more in 1968. The plan met with considerable initial confusion from enterprise managers who, throughout their careers, had underestimated their potential output in order to later exceed their quota. Also difficult
2268-407: The full-blown invasion of Czechoslovakia in 1968. Soviet officials and press nevertheless continued to advance the idea of the 1965 reform. Kosygin commented on June 10, 1970: The essence of the reform is, while perfecting centralized planning, to raise the initiative and interest of enterprises in the fullest use of production resources and to raise the efficiency of production in order to unify
2331-565: The history of the USSR was Alexei Kosygin , who was appointed head of government after the ousting of Nikita Khrushchev in 1964. However, Kosygin's prestige was weakened when he proposed the economic reform of 1965 . In 1991, upon Valentin Pavlov 's ascension to the premiership, the Council of Ministers was abolished and replaced with the Cabinet of Ministers . After the August coup of 1991 ,
2394-615: The interests of workers, enterprises, and society as a whole by means of the system of economic stimuli. Premier of the Soviet Union The Premier of the Soviet Union ( Russian : Глава Правительства СССР ) was the head of government of the Union of Soviet Socialist Republics (USSR). From 1923 to 1946, the name of the office was Chairman of the Council of People's Commissars , and from 1946 to 1991 its name
2457-475: The latter category were not nationalized, but instead placed under the guidance of the VSNKh, with the plan to group them into "trusts" based on production chains or geographic proximity . This model underwent various reorganizations, including the strengthening of edinonachalie , control of production units by a single manager. These single managers at times controlled a wide range of production activities within
2520-790: The majority of the cabinet members endorsed the coup, leading to the Cabinet of Ministers dissolving and being replaced by the Committee on the Operational Management of the Soviet Economy . The government of the Russian Soviet Federative Socialist Republic began seizing Soviet ministries in the aftermath of the coup, and by December 1991 the Soviet government had completely lost control of itself and shut down entirely. Under
2583-477: The market, and the old versions withdrawn. The economy grew more in 1966–1970 than it did in 1961–1965. Many enterprises were encouraged to sell or give away excess equipment, since all available capital was factored into the calculation of productivity. Certain measurements of efficiency improved. These included rising sales per rouble worth of capital and falling wages per rouble of sales. The enterprises rendered large portions of their profits, sometimes 80%, to
Eighth five-year plan (Soviet Union) - Misplaced Pages Continue
2646-474: The necessary labour and materials were simply undersupplied. One response to this problem in 1969 was to shift more incentives to the contractors. For the "optimal planners" this limited decentralization was inadequate, and the new importance assigned to "profit" was incomplete because enterprises did not control enough of the factors which might affect it. As a deputy director of TSEMI commented in 1966: We say: comrades, if you want to introduce profit, then it
2709-475: The need for military spending, which he said was necessary in response to the imperialist wars of the United States. This plan abandoned the slogan "Overtake and surpass the U.S.A.". The biggest change in quotas came in the sector of vehicles, which were scheduled for production at three times the rate specified in the previous plan. Whereas Soviet vehicle factories had formerly favored trucks and buses,
2772-399: The official Five-Year Plan. Ratification of the plan by the Supreme Soviet was delayed several times. By September 1967, no mention was made of the five-year plan and instead the Central Committee individual plans for 1968, 1969, and 1970. The wage reforms outlined in 1965, were, it was reported, implemented in Soviet factories during the course of the year 1966. The plan for 1968 included
2835-479: The personnel of an enterprise find it economically profitable to organize that work along lines that are profitable to the national economy as well. Unlike Liberman in 1962, Trapeznikov suggested that the need for reform had been embraced by party decisionmakers and would soon become a reality. In the following month, Pravda published six more articles from academicians, planners, and managers advocating reform. The last of these came from Liberman. This time, criticism
2898-568: The plan became crucial for practical implementation of theoretical ideas. According to official rationale for the reform, the increasing complexity of economic relations reduced the efficacy of economic planning and therefore reduced economic growth . It was recognized that the existing system of planning did not motivate enterprises to reach high rates of production or to introduce organizational or technical innovations. There were no incentives for that. Given more freedom to deviate publicly from party orthodoxy, newspapers offered new proposals for
2961-490: The power to fire workers. In fact, the reform gave new incentive for layoffs, which in some cases could increase profitability. (When these occurred, the workers did not have a 'social safety net' in place in the form of unemployment insurance and career assistance). To encourage accurate planning, enterprises now would be punished for performing below or above their planned goals. Enterprises would also pay rent for land and natural resources. The rationale for this practice
3024-409: The proportions in which different goods were produced. V. Trapeznikov advocated a position similar to Liberman's, in Pravda , August 1964, writing that [...] the time has come to discard the obsolete forms of economic management based on directive norms, and to pass over to a simpler, cheaper and more efficient type of control of the activities of enterprises. This control must be patterned so that
3087-591: The proposed reforms. (The Five-Year Plan dealt with a broad range of issues, with more of a focus on people's overall living conditions. It was expected to be implemented within the Party.) Most light industry was to transfer at the beginning of 1967. The remaining enterprises to switch over in two stages, taking effect on July 1, 1967, and January 1, 1968. The complete transfer of all enterprises proceeded steadily, if not exactly on schedule. By April 1, 1967, 2,500 enterprises, responsible for 20% of output, had switched. By
3150-431: The role of profit in the Soviet economic system. Rentabelnost' ("profitability", Russian : рентабельность ) and realizatsiya ("sales", Russian : реализация ) became the twin success indicators for enterprises. Rentabelnost' was defined in terms of the ratio between profits and capital, while realizatsiya (also meaning "implementation") depended on the total volume of sales. Success by these measurements led to
3213-534: The role of the Party in economic administration. Local officials were to oversee operations from a distance to ensure compliance with the spirit of the reforms. The plan called for more detailed and scientific central planning, including annual targets. These plans would be calculated using computer systems. Distribution of supplies and products would take place in different ways. Central planners would allocate certain scarce and vital goods. For others, enterprises could form "direct ties" within which they developed
SECTION 50
#17327723396863276-440: The same fund as wages. Now, enterprise managers had slightly more discretion over how to allocate them. They could move some amounts of money between the bonus fund and the social welfare fund. They also had more power to influence wages by classifying different workers. In practice, the bonuses had the greatest impact on the payment of elite personnel (technicians and "employees" as opposed to " workers "), thereby counteracting
3339-436: The system of set prices for their inputs and outputs—they had little control over the biggest decisions affecting their operations. Managers did have a responsibility to plan future gross output, which they chronically underestimated in order to later exceed the prediction. The managers then received bonuses ( premia ) for surplus product regardless of whether it was produced in a cost-effective manner or whether their enterprise
3402-410: The value of good to derive strictly from labor . This doctrine, elaborated in such works as Stalin's 1952 book, Economic Problems of Socialism in the USSR , described the price system as a capitalist relic which would eventually disappear from communist society. Nevertheless, computerized economics gained an important role for top planners, even while conventional Marxist–Leninist political economy
3465-549: Was Chairman of the Council of Ministers . During the dissolution of the Soviet Union in 1991, its name was briefly Prime Minister and later Chairman of the Committee on the Operational Management of the Soviet Economy . The first Soviet premier was the country's founder and first leader , Vladimir Lenin . After 1924, when General Secretary of the Communist Party Joseph Stalin rose to power,
3528-475: Was a set of planned changes in the economy of the USSR . A centerpiece of these changes was the introduction of profitability and sales as the two key indicators of enterprise success. Some of an enterprise's profits would go to three funds, used to reward workers and expand operations; most would go to the central budget. The reforms were introduced politically by Alexei Kosygin —who had just become Premier of
3591-663: Was a significant area of retrospective anti-Khrushchev criticism in the Soviet press. This 'reformist' economic tendency in the Soviet Union had corollaries and some mutual reinforcement in Eastern Europe. Kosygin criticized the inefficiency and inertia of economic policy under the previous administration. He presented a plan, including the ideas expressed by Liberman and Nemchinov, to the Communist Party Central Committee Plenum in September 1965. The Central Committee's acceptance of
3654-416: Was accomplished in early 1966. These were already profitable, well-positioned businesses, and reflected well on the reform in early evaluations. On July 1, 1966, 430 more enterprises were transferred; these included some large operations and themselves constituted 12% of total production. By the end of 1966, more than 704 enterprises had switched. The Eighth Five-Year Plan would have instantiated some of
3717-553: Was economic optimization. For example, land of differing quality required different inputs of manpower to achieve the same outputs, and thus should factor differently into the budget of an enterprise. Bank loans, to be repaid later with interest, would be used to fund more investment projects—to incentive the careful use of funds and the speedy creation of profit. Five different interest rates would be set, ranging from preferential to normal to punitive. An additional capital charge—i.e., tax—would be assessed for each enterprise based on
3780-665: Was muted. Several economic experiments were initiated to test Liberman's proposals. These began in 1964 with new policies for two garment factories: the Bolshevichka in Moscow and the Mayak in Gorky . When operations at the garment factories proved tolerably successful, the experiment was expanded to about 400 other enterprises, mostly in large cities. One experiment in Lviv involved
3843-484: Was profitable overall. The bonuses for output came in amounts sometimes equal to the managers' base salaries. The system also incentivized pointless increases in the size, weight, and cost of production outputs, simply because "more" had been produced. The economic reforms emerged during a period of great ideological debate over economic planning. More mathematical, " cybernetic ", viewpoints were at first considered deviant from orthodox Marxist economics , which considered
SECTION 60
#17327723396863906-542: Was taught in most schools and promoted for public consumption. The rising influence of statistical planning in the Soviet economy was reflected in the creation of the Central Economic Mathematical Institute (Центральный экономико-математический институт; TSEMI), led by Vasily Sergeevich Nemchinov . Nemchinov, along with linear programming inventor Leonid Kantorovich and investment analyst Viktor Valentinovich Novozhilov , received
3969-465: Was the requirement to comply with the new directives before all aspects of the economy (i.e., prices, resource availability) had shifted over. And the reluctance of certain bureaucrats to comply with the new policies was the subject of sustained criticism in the press, including multiple editorials by Liberman himself. In April 1966, for example, Liberman recommended creating a "brain trust of the reconstruction" which could veto counter-reformist policies in
#685314