In mathematical economics , the Arrow–Debreu model is a theoretical general equilibrium model. It posits that under certain economic assumptions ( convex preferences , perfect competition , and demand independence), there must be a set of prices such that aggregate supplies will equal aggregate demands for every commodity in the economy.
92-438: The model is central to the theory of general (economic) equilibrium , and it is used as a general reference for other microeconomic models. It was proposed by Kenneth Arrow , Gérard Debreu in 1954, and Lionel W. McKenzie independently in 1954, with later improvements in 1959. The A-D model is one of the most general models of competitive economy and is a crucial part of general equilibrium theory , as it can be used to prove
184-560: A 1979 article, Nicholas Georgescu-Roegen complains: "There are endeavors that now pass for the most desirable kind of economic contributions although they are just plain mathematical exercises, not only without any economic substance but also without any mathematical value." He cites as an example a paper that assumes more traders in existence than there are points in the set of real numbers. Although modern models in general equilibrium theory demonstrate that under certain circumstances prices will indeed converge to equilibria, critics hold that
276-541: A complete set of prices for contracts such as "1 ton of Winter red wheat, delivered on 3rd of January in Minneapolis, if there is a hurricane in Florida during December". A general equilibrium model with complete markets of this sort seems to be a long way from describing the workings of real economies, however, its proponents argue that it is still useful as a simplified guide as to how real economies function. Some of
368-450: A consumer better off without leaving another consumer worse off. In a pure exchange economy, a sufficient condition for the first welfare theorem to hold is that preferences be locally nonsatiated . The first welfare theorem also holds for economies with production regardless of the properties of the production function. Implicitly, the theorem assumes complete markets and perfect information. In an economy with externalities , for example, it
460-494: A contract specifies, for example, a good to be delivered and the date at which it is to be delivered. The Arrow–Debreu model of intertemporal equilibrium contains forward markets for all goods at all dates. No markets exist at any future dates. Third, suppose contracts specify states of nature which affect whether a commodity is to be delivered: "A contract for the transfer of a commodity now specifies, in addition to its physical properties, its location and its date, an event on
552-539: A deeper result than proving the two Fundamental Theorems. Another method of proof of existence, global analysis , uses Sard's lemma and the Baire category theorem ; this method was pioneered by Gérard Debreu and Stephen Smale . Starr (1969) applied the Shapley–Folkman–Starr theorem to prove that even without convex preferences there exists an approximate equilibrium. The Shapley–Folkman–Starr results bound
644-707: A distribution of endowments { r i } i ∈ I {\displaystyle \{r^{i}\}_{i\in I}} and private ownerships { α i , j } i ∈ I , j ∈ J {\displaystyle \{\alpha ^{i,j}\}_{i\in I,j\in J}} of the producers, such that the given state is a market equilibrium state for some price vector p ∈ R + + N {\displaystyle p\in \mathbb {R} _{++}^{N}} . Proof idea: any Pareto-optimal consumption plan
736-433: A function f ( p ) = max ( 0 , p + γ Z ~ ( p ) ) ∑ n max ( 0 , p n + γ Z ~ ( p ) n ) {\displaystyle f(p)={\frac {\max(0,p+\gamma {\tilde {Z}}(p))}{\sum _{n}\max(0,p_{n}+\gamma {\tilde {Z}}(p)_{n})}}} on
828-429: A good is simplified by just looking at the price of one good, and assuming that the prices of all other goods remain constant. The Marshallian theory of supply and demand is an example of partial equilibrium analysis. Partial equilibrium analysis is adequate when the first-order effects of a shift in the demand curve do not shift the supply curve. Anglo-American economists became more interested in general equilibrium in
920-431: A large consumption side, nonconvexities in preferences do not destroy the standard results of, say Debreu's theory of value. In the same way, if indivisibilities in the production sector are small with respect to the size of the economy, [ . . . ] then standard results are affected in only a minor way. To this text, Guesnerie appended the following footnote: The derivation of these results in general form has been one of
1012-545: A method for solving the Arrow–Debreu General Equilibrium system in a numerical fashion. This was first implemented by John Shoven and John Whalley (students of Scarf at Yale) in 1972 and 1973, and were a popular method up through the 1970s. In the 1980s however, AGE models faded from popularity due to their inability to provide a precise solution and its high cost of computation. Computable general equilibrium (CGE) models surpassed and replaced AGE models in
SECTION 10
#17327796215441104-594: A plan is Pareto-efficient with respect to a starting endowment r {\displaystyle r} , iff it is feasible, and there does not exist another feasible plan that is strictly better in Pareto ordering. In general, there are a whole continuum of Pareto-efficient plans for each starting endowment r {\displaystyle r} . With the set up, we have two fundamental theorems of welfare economics: First fundamental theorem of welfare economics — Any market equilibrium state
1196-464: A price equilibrium with transfers. The first attempt in neoclassical economics to model prices for a whole economy was made by Léon Walras . Walras' Elements of Pure Economics provides a succession of models, each taking into account more aspects of a real economy (two commodities, many commodities, production, growth, money). Some think Walras was unsuccessful and that the later models in this series are inconsistent. In particular, Walras's model
1288-453: A shift in the demand curve of the original industry under these assumptions includes a shift in the supply curve of substitutes for that industry's product, and consequent shifts in the original industry's supply curve. General equilibrium is designed to investigate such interactions between markets. Continental European economists made important advances in the 1930s. Walras' arguments for the existence of general equilibrium often were based on
1380-413: A single individual) or the gross substitute property then likewise the equilibrium will be unique. All methods of establishing uniqueness can be thought of as establishing that each equilibrium has the same positive local index, in which case by the index theorem there can be but one such equilibrium. Given that equilibria may not be unique, it is of some interest to ask whether any particular equilibrium
1472-1388: A wide freedom in choosing the master plan, but any reasonable planner should agree that, if someone's utility can be increased, while everyone else's is not decreased, then it is a better plan. That is, the Pareto ordering should be followed. Define the Pareto ordering on the set of all plans ( ( x i ) i ∈ I , ( y j ) j ∈ J ) {\displaystyle ((x^{i})_{i\in I},(y^{j})_{j\in J})} by ( ( x i ) i ∈ I , ( y j ) j ∈ J ) ⪰ ( ( x ′ i ) i ∈ I , ( y ′ j ) j ∈ J ) {\displaystyle ((x^{i})_{i\in I},(y^{j})_{j\in J})\succeq ((x'^{i})_{i\in I},(y'^{j})_{j\in J})} iff x i ⪰ i x ′ i {\displaystyle x^{i}\succeq ^{i}x'^{i}} for all i ∈ I {\displaystyle i\in I} . Then, we say that
1564-442: Is A model organized around the tâtonnement process has been said to be a model of a centrally planned economy , not a decentralized market economy. Some research has tried to develop general equilibrium models with other processes. In particular, some economists have developed models in which agents can trade at out-of-equilibrium prices and such trades can affect the equilibria to which the economy tends. Particularly noteworthy are
1656-407: Is separated by a hyperplane from the set of attainable consumption plans. The slope of the hyperplane would be the equilibrium prices. Verify that under such prices, each producer and household would find the given state optimal. Verify that Walras's law holds, and so the expenditures match income plus profit, and so it is possible to provide each household with exactly the necessary budget. Since
1748-700: Is Pareto-efficient. The price hyperplane separates the attainable productions and the Pareto-better consumptions. That is, the hyperplane ⟨ p ∗ , q ⟩ = ⟨ p ∗ , D ( p ∗ ) ⟩ {\displaystyle \langle p^{*},q\rangle =\langle p^{*},D(p^{*})\rangle } separates r + P P S r {\displaystyle r+PPS_{r}} and U + + {\displaystyle U_{++}} , where U + + {\displaystyle U_{++}}
1840-601: Is a continuous transformation of a compact set into itself; although compact, the unit circle is non-convex. In contrast, the same rotation applied to the convex hull of the unit circle leaves the point (0,0) fixed. Notice that the Kakutani theorem does not assert that there exists exactly one fixed point. Reflecting the unit disk across the y-axis leaves a vertical segment fixed, so that this reflection has an infinite number of fixed points. The assumption of convexity precluded many applications, which were discussed in
1932-411: Is a list of prices for each commodity, which every producer and household takes (there is no bargaining behavior—every producer and household is a price taker ). The market has no utility or profit. Instead, the market aims to choose a market price vector such that, even though each household and producer is maximizing their utility and profit, their consumption and production plans "harmonize." That is, "
SECTION 20
#17327796215442024-451: Is an equilibrium price vector for the restricted market, then it is also an equilibrium price vector for the unrestricted market. Furthermore, we have D ~ i ( p ) = D i ( p ) , S ~ j ( p ) = S j ( p ) {\displaystyle {\tilde {D}}^{i}(p)=D^{i}(p),{\tilde {S}}^{j}(p)=S^{j}(p)} . As
2116-599: Is at least locally unique. If so, then comparative statics can be applied as long as the shocks to the system are not too large. As stated above, in a regular economy equilibria will be finite, hence locally unique. One reassuring result, due to Debreu, is that "most" economies are regular. Work by Michael Mandler (1999) has challenged this claim. The Arrow–Debreu–McKenzie model is neutral between models of production functions as continuously differentiable and as formed from (linear combinations of) fixed coefficient processes. Mandler accepts that, under either model of production,
2208-850: Is attainable, and any outside is not. Find the market price p {\displaystyle p} . Claim: p ≻ 0 {\displaystyle p\succ 0} . We have by construction ⟨ p , ∑ i ∈ I x i ⟩ = c {\displaystyle \langle p,\sum _{i\in I}x^{i}\rangle =c} , and ⟨ p , V ⟩ ≤ c {\displaystyle \langle p,V\rangle \leq c} . Now we claim: ⟨ p , U + + ⟩ > c {\displaystyle \langle p,U_{++}\rangle >c} . General equilibrium In economics , general equilibrium theory attempts to explain
2300-636: Is capable of transforming t {\displaystyle t} units of commodity 1 into ( t + 1 ) 2 − 1 {\displaystyle {\sqrt {(t+1)^{2}-1}}} units of commodity 2, and we have p 1 / p 2 < 1 {\displaystyle p_{1}/p_{2}<1} , then the producer can create plans with infinite profit, thus Π j ( p ) = + ∞ {\displaystyle \Pi ^{j}(p)=+\infty } , and S j ( p ) {\displaystyle S^{j}(p)}
2392-437: Is chosen to be large enough such that: Each requirement is satisfiable. The two requirements together imply that the restriction is not a real restriction when the production plans and consumption plans are " interior " to the restriction. These two propositions imply that equilibria for the restricted market are equilibria for the unrestricted market: Theorem — If p {\displaystyle p}
2484-451: Is efficient, it may not be that every efficient allocation of resources can be part of an equilibrium. However, the second theorem states that every Pareto efficient allocation can be supported as an equilibrium by some set of prices. In other words, all that is required to reach a particular Pareto efficient outcome is a redistribution of initial endowments of the agents after which the market can be left alone to do its work. This suggests that
2576-465: Is efficient, neither of the above two theorems say anything about the equilibrium existing in the first place. To guarantee that an equilibrium exists, it suffices that consumer preferences be strictly convex . With enough consumers, the convexity assumption can be relaxed both for existence and the second welfare theorem. Similarly, but less plausibly, convex feasible production sets suffice for existence; convexity excludes economies of scale . Proofs of
2668-410: Is exactly zero, then every household has spent all their budget. Else, some household is restricted to spend only part of their budget. Therefore, that household's consumption bundle is on the boundary of the restriction, that is, ‖ D ~ i ( p ) ‖ = C {\displaystyle \|{\tilde {D}}^{i}(p)\|=C} . We have chosen (in
2760-591: Is finding a Pareto-optimal plan for the economy. Intuitively, one can consider the problem of welfare economics to be the problem faced by a master planner for the whole economy: given starting endowment r {\displaystyle r} for the entire society, the planner must pick a feasible master plan of production and consumption plans ( ( x i ) i ∈ I , ( y j ) j ∈ J ) {\displaystyle ((x^{i})_{i\in I},(y^{j})_{j\in J})} . The master planner has
2852-588: Is guaranteed. Walras also proposed a dynamic process by which general equilibrium might be reached, that of the tâtonnement or groping process. The tâtonnement process is a model for investigating stability of equilibria. Prices are announced (perhaps by an "auctioneer"), and agents state how much of each good they would like to offer (supply) or purchase (demand). No transactions and no production take place at disequilibrium prices. Instead, prices are lowered for goods with positive prices and excess supply . Prices are raised for goods with excess demand. The question for
Arrow–Debreu model - Misplaced Pages Continue
2944-399: Is not as clear as it used to be, since much of modern macroeconomics has emphasized microeconomic foundations , and has constructed general equilibrium models of macroeconomic fluctuations . General equilibrium macroeconomic models usually have a simplified structure that only incorporates a few markets, like a "goods market" and a "financial market". In contrast, general equilibrium models in
3036-423: Is possible for equilibria to arise that are not efficient. The first welfare theorem is informative in the sense that it points to the sources of inefficiency in markets. Under the assumptions above, any market equilibrium is tautologically efficient. Therefore, when equilibria arise that are not efficient, the market system itself is not to blame, but rather some sort of market failure . Even if every equilibrium
3128-654: Is precisely correct; once there were beliefs, now there was knowledge. The Arrow-Debreu model, as communicated in the Theory of Value, changed basic thinking and quickly became the standard model of price theory. It is the "benchmark” model in Finance, International Trade, Public Finance, Transportation, and even macroeconomics... In rather short order, it was no longer "as it is" in Marshall, Hicks, and Samuelson; rather, it became "as it is" in Theory of Value. This section follows
3220-563: Is provided by the Arrow–Debreu– McKenzie model, developed jointly by Kenneth Arrow , Gérard Debreu , and Lionel W. McKenzie in the 1950s. Debreu presents this model in Theory of Value (1959) as an axiomatic model, following the style of mathematics promoted by Nicolas Bourbaki . In such an approach, the interpretation of the terms in the theory (e.g., goods, prices) are not fixed by the axioms. Three important interpretations of
3312-406: Is that if consumers lack adequate means to transfer their wealth from one time period to another and the future is risky, there is nothing to necessarily tie any price ratio down to the relevant marginal rate of substitution , which is the standard requirement for Pareto optimality. Under some conditions the economy may still be constrained Pareto optimal , meaning that a central authority limited to
3404-531: Is the set of aggregates of all possible consumption plans that are strictly Pareto-better. The attainable productions are on the lower side of the price hyperplane, while the Pareto-better consumptions are strictly on the upper side of the price hyperplane. Thus any Pareto-better plan is not attainable. Second fundamental theorem of welfare economics — For any total endowment r {\displaystyle r} , and any Pareto-efficient state achievable using that endowment, there exists
3496-776: Is the set of all ∑ i ∈ I x ′ i {\displaystyle \sum _{i\in I}x'^{i}} , such that ∀ i ∈ I , x ′ i ∈ C P S i , x ′ i ⪰ i x i {\displaystyle \forall i\in I,x'^{i}\in CPS^{i},x'^{i}\succeq ^{i}x^{i}} , and ∃ i ∈ I , x ′ i ≻ i x i {\displaystyle \exists i\in I,x'^{i}\succ ^{i}x^{i}} . That is, it
3588-529: Is undefined. Consequently, we define " restricted market " to be the same market, except there is a universal upper bound C {\displaystyle C} , such that every producer is required to use a production plan ‖ y j ‖ ≤ C {\displaystyle \|y^{j}\|\leq C} . Each household is required to use a consumption plan ‖ x i ‖ ≤ C {\displaystyle \|x^{i}\|\leq C} . Denote
3680-695: Is unstable and there is a shock, the economy will wind up at a different set of allocations and prices once the convergence process terminates. However, stability depends not only on the number of equilibria but also on the type of the process that guides price changes (for a specific type of price adjustment process see Walrasian auction ). Consequently, some researchers have focused on plausible adjustment processes that guarantee system stability, i.e., that guarantee convergence of prices and allocations to some equilibrium. When more than one stable equilibrium exists, where one ends up will depend on where one begins. The theorems that have been mostly conclusive when related to
3772-510: The Journal of Political Economy from 1959 to 1961 by Francis M. Bator, M. J. Farrell , Tjalling Koopmans , and Thomas J. Rothenberg. Ross M. Starr ( 1969 ) proved the existence of economic equilibria when some consumer preferences need not be convex . In his paper, Starr proved that a "convexified" economy has general equilibria that are closely approximated by "quasi-equilbria" of
Arrow–Debreu model - Misplaced Pages Continue
3864-569: The 1870s, particularly the work of French economist Léon Walras in his pioneering 1874 work Elements of Pure Economics . The theory reached its modern form with the work of Lionel W. McKenzie (Walrasian theory), Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu (Hicksian theory) in the 1950s. Broadly speaking, general equilibrium tries to give an understanding of the whole economy using a "bottom-up" approach, starting with individual markets and agents. Therefore, general equilibrium theory has traditionally been classified as part of microeconomics . The difference
3956-405: The 1970s general equilibrium analysis remained theoretical. With advances in computing power and the development of input–output tables, it became possible to model national economies, or even the world economy, and attempts were made to solve for general equilibrium prices and quantities empirically. Applied general equilibrium (AGE) models were pioneered by Herbert Scarf in 1967, and offered
4048-508: The 1970s, states that the aggregate excess demand function inherits only certain properties of individual's demand functions, and that these ( continuity , homogeneity of degree zero , Walras' law and boundary behavior when prices are near zero) are the only real restriction one can expect from an aggregate excess demand function. Any such function can represent the excess demand of an economy populated with rational utility-maximizing individuals. There has been much research on conditions when
4140-503: The Arrow-Debreu-McKenzie model is thus fully subject to the dilemmas of factor price theory. Some have questioned the practical applicability of the general equilibrium approach based on the possibility of non-uniqueness of equilibria. In a typical general equilibrium model the prices that prevail "when the dust settles" are simply those that coordinate the demands of various consumers for various goods. But this raises
4232-560: The Hahn process, the Edgeworth process and the Fisher process. The data determining Arrow-Debreu equilibria include initial endowments of capital goods. If production and trade occur out of equilibrium, these endowments will be changed further complicating the picture. In a real economy, however, trading, as well as production and consumption, goes on out of equilibrium. It follows that, in
4324-417: The assumptions given, makes them utility maximizers . The households choose the consumption plan with the highest utility they can afford using their budget. The producers can transform bundles of commodities into other bundles of commodities. The producers have no separate utility functions. Instead, they are all purely profit maximizers. The market is only capable of "choosing" a market price vector, which
4416-460: The assumptions necessary for these results are extremely strong. As well as stringent restrictions on excess demand functions, the necessary assumptions include perfect rationality of individuals; complete information about all prices both now and in the future; and the conditions necessary for perfect competition . However, some results from experimental economics suggest that even in circumstances where there are few, imperfectly informed agents,
4508-504: The behavior of supply, demand, and prices in a whole economy with several or many interacting markets, by seeking to prove that the interaction of demand and supply will result in an overall general equilibrium . General equilibrium theory contrasts with the theory of partial equilibrium , which analyzes a specific part of an economy while its other factors are held constant. In general equilibrium, constant influences are considered to be noneconomic, or in other words, considered to be beyond
4600-408: The conditions under which an equilibrium will be efficient, which efficient equilibria can be achieved, when an equilibrium is guaranteed to exist and when the equilibrium will be unique and stable. The First Fundamental Welfare Theorem asserts that market equilibria are Pareto efficient . In other words, the allocation of goods in the equilibria is such that there is no reallocation which would leave
4692-474: The corresponding quantities on the restricted market with a tilde. So, for example, Z ~ ( p ) {\displaystyle {\tilde {Z}}(p)} is the excess demand function on the restricted market. C {\displaystyle C} is chosen to be "large enough" for the economy so that the restriction is not in effect under equilibrium conditions (see next section). In detail, C {\displaystyle C}
SECTION 50
#17327796215444784-403: The counting of equations and variables. Such arguments are inadequate for non-linear systems of equations and do not imply that equilibrium prices and quantities cannot be negative, a meaningless solution for his models. The replacement of certain equations by inequalities and the use of more rigorous mathematics improved general equilibrium modeling. The modern conception of general equilibrium
4876-420: The course of convergence to equilibrium (assuming that occurs), endowments change. In turn this changes the set of equilibria. Put more succinctly, the set of equilibria is path dependent ... [This path dependence] makes the calculation of equilibria corresponding to the initial state of the system essentially irrelevant. What matters is the equilibrium that the economy will reach from given initial endowments, not
4968-463: The demand for bread might be affected by a change in bakers' wages, with a consequent effect on the price of bread. Calculating the equilibrium price of just one good, in theory, requires an analysis that accounts for all of the millions of different goods that are available. It is often assumed that agents are price takers , and under that assumption two common notions of equilibrium exist: Walrasian, or competitive equilibrium , and its generalization:
5060-555: The distance from an "approximate" economic equilibrium to an equilibrium of a "convexified" economy, when the number of agents exceeds the dimension of the goods. Following Starr's paper, the Shapley–Folkman–Starr results were "much exploited in the theoretical literature", according to Guesnerie, who wrote the following: some key results obtained under the convexity assumption remain (approximately) relevant in circumstances where convexity fails. For example, in economies with
5152-629: The entire sequence of prices clears all markets at all times. A generalization of the sequential market arrangement is the temporary equilibrium structure, where market clearing at a point in time is conditional on expectations of future prices which need not be market clearing ones. Although the Arrow–Debreu–McKenzie model is set out in terms of some arbitrary numéraire , the model does not encompass money. Frank Hahn , for example, has investigated whether general equilibrium models can be developed in which money enters in some essential way. One of
5244-503: The equilibrium that it would have been in, given initial endowments, had prices happened to be just right. – ( Franklin Fisher ). The Arrow–Debreu model in which all trade occurs in futures contracts at time zero requires a very large number of markets to exist. It is equivalent under complete markets to a sequential equilibrium concept in which spot markets for goods and assets open at each date-state event (they are not equivalent under incomplete markets); market clearing then requires that
5336-428: The equilibrium will be unique, or which at least will limit the number of equilibria. One result states that under mild assumptions the number of equilibria will be finite (see regular economy ) and odd (see index theorem ). Furthermore, if an economy as a whole, as characterized by an aggregate excess demand function, has the revealed preference property (which is a much stronger condition than revealed preferences for
5428-534: The essential questions he introduces, often referred to as the Hahn's problem is: "Can one construct an equilibrium where money has value?" The goal is to find models in which existence of money can alter the equilibrium solutions, perhaps because the initial position of agents depends on monetary prices. Some critics of general equilibrium modeling contend that much research in these models constitutes exercises in pure mathematics with no connection to actual economies. In
5520-620: The existence of general equilibrium (or Walrasian equilibrium ) of an economy. In general, there may be many equilibria. Arrow (1972) and Debreu (1983) were separately awarded the Nobel Prize in Economics for their development of the model. McKenzie, however, did not receive the award. The contents of both theorems [fundamental theorems of welfare economics] are old beliefs in economics. Arrow and Debreu have recently treated this question with techniques permitting proofs. This statement
5612-626: The existence of equilibrium traditionally rely on fixed-point theorems such as Brouwer fixed-point theorem for functions (or, more generally, the Kakutani fixed-point theorem for set-valued functions ). See Competitive equilibrium#Existence of a competitive equilibrium . The proof was first due to Lionel McKenzie , and Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu . In fact, the converse also holds, according to Uzawa 's derivation of Brouwer's fixed point theorem from Walras's law. Following Uzawa's theorem, many mathematical economists consider proving existence
SECTION 60
#17327796215445704-469: The existence of general equilibria by invoking the Kakutani fixed-point theorem on the fixed points of a continuous function from a compact , convex set into itself. In the Arrow–Debreu approach, convexity is essential, because such fixed-point theorems are inapplicable to non-convex sets. For example, the rotation of the unit circle by 90 degrees lacks fixed points, although this rotation
5796-448: The function f {\displaystyle f} is a contraction . This is unsurprising, as there is no guarantee (without further assumptions) that any market equilibrium is a stable equilibrium. Corollary — An equilibrium price vector exists for the unrestricted market, at which point the unrestricted market satisfies Walras's law. In 1954, McKenzie and the pair Arrow and Debreu independently proved
5888-408: The households in proportion to how much stock each household holds for the producer j {\displaystyle j} . Ownership is imposed initially, and the households may not sell, buy, create, or discard them. The households receive a budget, income from selling endowments, and dividend from producer profits. The households possess preferences over bundles of commodities, which, under
5980-421: The industry supply curves will not slope up. If an industry uses an appreciable amount of that factor of production, an increase in the output of that industry will exhibit increasing costs. But such a factor is likely to be used in substitutes for the industry's product, and an increased price of that factor will have effects on the supply of those substitutes. Consequently, Sraffa argued, the first-order effects of
6072-421: The initial endowments will not be consistent with a continuum of equilibria, except for a set of Lebesgue measure zero. However, endowments change with time in the model and this evolution of endowments is determined by the decisions of agents (e.g., firms) in the model. Agents in the model have an interest in equilibria being indeterminate: Indeterminacy, moreover, is not just a technical nuisance; it undermines
6164-545: The initial quantities of capital goods as given, but adopted a short run model in which the prices of capital goods vary with time and the own rate of interest varies across capital goods.) Walras was the first to lay down a research program widely followed by 20th-century economists. In particular, the Walrasian agenda included the investigation of when equilibria are unique and stable— Walras' Lesson 7 shows neither uniqueness, nor stability, nor even existence of an equilibrium
6256-442: The issues of efficiency and equity can be separated and need not involve a trade-off. The conditions for the second theorem are stronger than those for the first, as consumers' preferences and production sets now need to be convex (convexity roughly corresponds to the idea of diminishing marginal rates of substitution i.e. "the average of two equally good bundles is better than either of the two bundles"). Even though every equilibrium
6348-973: The last piece of the construction, we define Walras's law : Walras's law can be interpreted on both sides: Theorem — Z ~ {\displaystyle {\tilde {Z}}} satisfies weak Walras's law: For all p ∈ R + + N {\displaystyle p\in \mathbb {R} _{++}^{N}} , ⟨ p , Z ~ ( p ) ⟩ ≤ 0 {\displaystyle \langle p,{\tilde {Z}}(p)\rangle \leq 0} and if ⟨ p , Z ~ ( p ) ⟩ < 0 {\displaystyle \langle p,{\tilde {Z}}(p)\rangle <0} , then Z ~ ( p ) n > 0 {\displaystyle {\tilde {Z}}(p)_{n}>0} for some n {\displaystyle n} . If total excess demand value
6440-436: The late 1920s and 1930s after Piero Sraffa 's demonstration that Marshallian economists cannot account for the forces thought to account for the upward-slope of the supply curve for a consumer good. If an industry uses little of a factor of production, a small increase in the output of that industry will not bid the price of that factor up. To a first-order approximation, firms in the industry will experience constant costs, and
6532-519: The major achievements of postwar economic theory. In particular, the Shapley-Folkman-Starr results were incorporated in the theory of general economic equilibria and in the theory of market failures and of public economics . Although generally (assuming convexity) an equilibrium will exist and will be efficient, the conditions under which it will be unique are much stronger. The Sonnenschein–Mantel–Debreu theorem , proven in
6624-405: The market at the beginning. If they wish to retain some of the endowments, they would have to repurchase them from the market later. The endowments may be working hours, land use, tons of corn, etc. The households possess proportional ownerships of producers, which can be thought of as joint-stock companies . The profit made by producer j {\displaystyle j} is divided among
6716-473: The market clears ". In other words, the market is playing the role of a " Walrasian auctioneer ." In general, we write indices of agents as superscripts and vector coordinate indices as subscripts. The functions D i ( p ) , S j ( p ) {\displaystyle D^{i}(p),S^{j}(p)} are not necessarily well-defined for all price vectors p {\displaystyle p} . For example, if producer 1
6808-481: The mathematician is under what conditions such a process will terminate in equilibrium where demand equates to supply for goods with positive prices and demand does not exceed supply for goods with a price of zero. Walras was not able to provide a definitive answer to this question (see Unresolved Problems in General Equilibrium below). In partial equilibrium analysis, the determination of the price of
6900-433: The microeconomic tradition typically involve a multitude of different goods markets. They are usually complex and require computers to calculate numerical solutions . In a market system the prices and production of all goods, including the price of money and interest , are interrelated. A change in the price of one good, say bread, may affect another price, such as bakers' wages. If bakers don't differ in tastes from others,
6992-611: The mid-1980s, as the CGE model was able to provide relatively quick and large computable models for a whole economy, and was the preferred method of governments and the World Bank . CGE models are heavily used today, and while 'AGE' and 'CGE' is used inter-changeably in the literature, Scarf-type AGE models have not been constructed since the mid-1980s, and the CGE literature at current is not based on Arrow-Debreu and General Equilibrium Theory as discussed in this article. CGE models, and what
7084-462: The occurrence of which the transfer is conditional. This new definition of a commodity allows one to obtain a theory of [risk] free from any probability concept..." These interpretations can be combined. So the complete Arrow–Debreu model can be said to apply when goods are identified by when they are to be delivered, where they are to be delivered and under what circumstances they are to be delivered, as well as their intrinsic nature. So there would be
7176-489: The original economy; Starr's proof used the Shapley–Folkman theorem . ( Uzawa , 1962) showed that the existence of general equilibrium in an economy characterized by a continuous excess demand function fulfilling Walras's Law is equivalent to Brouwer fixed-Point theorem. Thus, the use of Brouwer's fixed-point theorem is essential for showing that the equilibrium exists in general. In welfare economics, one possible concern
7268-447: The presentation in, which is based on. The Arrow–Debreu model models an economy as a combination of three kinds of agents: the households, the producers, and the market. The households and producers transact with the market but not with each other directly. The households possess endowments (bundles of commodities they begin with), one may think of as "inheritance." For mathematical clarity, all households must sell all their endowment to
7360-598: The previous section) C {\displaystyle C} to be so large that even if all the producers coordinate, they would still fall short of meeting the demand. Consequently there exists some commodity n {\displaystyle n} such that D ~ i ( p ) n > S ~ ( p ) n + r n {\displaystyle {\tilde {D}}^{i}(p)_{n}>{\tilde {S}}(p)_{n}+r_{n}} Theorem — An equilibrium price vector exists for
7452-417: The price simplex, where γ {\displaystyle \gamma } is a fixed positive constant. By the weak Walras law, this function is well-defined. By Brouwer's fixed-point theorem, it has a fixed point. By the weak Walras law, this fixed point is a market equilibrium. Note that the above proof does not give an iterative algorithm for finding any equilibrium, as there is no guarantee that
7544-492: The price-taking assumption of competitive models. Since arbitrary small manipulations of factor supplies can dramatically increase a factor's price, factor owners will not take prices to be parametric. When technology is modeled by (linear combinations) of fixed coefficient processes, optimizing agents will drive endowments to be such that a continuum of equilibria exist: The endowments where indeterminacy occurs systematically arise through time and therefore cannot be dismissed;
7636-428: The question of how these prices and allocations have been arrived at, and whether any (temporary) shock to the economy will cause it to converge back to the same outcome that prevailed before the shock. This is the question of stability of the equilibrium, and it can be readily seen that it is related to the question of uniqueness. If there are multiple equilibria, then some of them will be unstable. Then, if an equilibrium
7728-474: The recent work in general equilibrium has in fact explored the implications of incomplete markets , which is to say an intertemporal economy with uncertainty, where there do not exist sufficiently detailed contracts that would allow agents to fully allocate their consumption and resources through time. While it has been shown that such economies will generally still have an equilibrium, the outcome may no longer be Pareto optimal . The basic intuition for this result
7820-585: The restricted market, at which point the restricted market satisfies Walras's law. By definition of equilibrium, if p {\displaystyle p} is an equilibrium price vector for the restricted market, then at that point, the restricted market satisfies Walras's law. Z ~ {\displaystyle {\tilde {Z}}} is continuous since all S ~ j , D ~ i {\displaystyle {\tilde {S}}^{j},{\tilde {D}}^{i}} are continuous. Define
7912-408: The resulting prices and allocations may wind up resembling those of a perfectly competitive market (although certainly not a stable general equilibrium in all markets). Frank Hahn defends general equilibrium modeling on the grounds that it provides a negative function. General equilibrium models show what the economy would have to be like for an unregulated economy to be Pareto efficient . Until
8004-485: The same type and number of contracts as the individual agents may not be able to improve upon the outcome, what is needed is the introduction of a full set of possible contracts. Hence, one implication of the theory of incomplete markets is that inefficiency may be a result of underdeveloped financial institutions or credit constraints faced by some members of the public. Research still continues in this area. Basic questions in general equilibrium analysis are concerned with
8096-464: The scope of economic analysis. The noneconomic influences may change given changes in the economic factors however, and therefore the prediction accuracy of an equilibrium model may depend on the independence of the economic factors from noneconomic ones. General equilibrium theory both studies economies using the model of equilibrium pricing and seeks to determine in which circumstances the assumptions of general equilibrium will hold. The theory dates to
8188-515: The stability of a typical general equilibrium model are closed related to that of the most local stability. Research building on the Arrow–Debreu–McKenzie model has revealed some problems with the model. The Sonnenschein–Mantel–Debreu results show that, essentially, any restrictions on the shape of excess demand functions are stringent. Some think this implies that the Arrow–Debreu model lacks empirical content. Therefore, an unsolved problem
8280-803: The state is attainable, we have ∑ i ∈ I x i ⪯ ∑ j ∈ J y j + r {\displaystyle \sum _{i\in I}x^{i}\preceq \sum _{j\in J}y^{j}+r} . The equality does not necessarily hold, so we define the set of attainable aggregate consumptions V := { r + y − z : y ∈ P P S , z ⪰ 0 } {\displaystyle V:=\{r+y-z:y\in PPS,z\succeq 0\}} . Any aggregate consumption bundle in V {\displaystyle V}
8372-484: The terms of the theory have been often cited. First, suppose commodities are distinguished by the location where they are delivered. Then the Arrow-Debreu model is a spatial model of, for example, international trade. Second, suppose commodities are distinguished by when they are delivered. That is, suppose all markets equilibrate at some initial instant of time. Agents in the model purchase and sell contracts, where
8464-446: Was a long-run model in which prices of capital goods are the same whether they appear as inputs or outputs and in which the same rate of profits is earned in all lines of industry. This is inconsistent with the quantities of capital goods being taken as data. But when Walras introduced capital goods in his later models, he took their quantities as given, in arbitrary ratios. (In contrast, Kenneth Arrow and Gérard Debreu continued to take
#543456